13.12.2012 Views

ancient cities

ancient cities

ancient cities

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

ecomes: How are those interests reconciled in a way<br />

that governance is possible? This question returns us<br />

to the composition and accommodation processes of<br />

governing regimes. By focusing on these two<br />

aspects, regime theory puts the agency and, thus,<br />

the politics back into urban governance and policy.<br />

In restoring agency and politics, regime theory also<br />

restores accountability. If city governments are not<br />

on a deterministic path but, rather, do have and do<br />

make choices, then we can hold decision makers<br />

accountable, and we can pursue alternative policy<br />

directions.<br />

Regime Typologies<br />

Linking regime composition to policy outcomes,<br />

Stone identifies different types of regimes, so different<br />

that he develops a typology to distinguish<br />

them. The logic behind the typology is to underscore<br />

the relationship between policy agendas, on<br />

the one hand, and resources and levels of coordination<br />

necessary to execute those agendas on the<br />

other hand. In ascending order of complexity, we<br />

have maintenance regimes, developmental regimes,<br />

middle-class progressive regimes, and finally, lower-<br />

class opportunity expansion regimes.<br />

Maintenance regimes, which are essentially<br />

caretaker administrations, tend to the basic service<br />

delivery functions of municipal government and<br />

not much more. Consequently, they do not require<br />

much in the way of coordination of actors or<br />

resources. Developmental regimes, which are the<br />

most typical, are organized around the deliberate<br />

alteration of land use patterns to facilitate economic<br />

growth or forestall economic decline. These<br />

regimes are characterized by significant controversy;<br />

a need to coordinate institutional actors and<br />

resources; the generation of selective incentives<br />

such as contracts, jobs, and the like; and the insulation<br />

of as much decision making as possible to<br />

dampen conflict.<br />

Middle-class progressive regimes are centered<br />

around quality of life issues of the environmental<br />

and aesthetic variety, economic issues such as<br />

affordable housing and affirmative action, and<br />

social programs geared toward the less well off. All<br />

of these concerns require regulation or concessions<br />

from private-sector interests. Thus, the cooperative<br />

model that characterizes developmental regimes is<br />

Regime Theory<br />

645<br />

replaced by a more coercive posture. Given the<br />

ability of business to exit, middle-class progressive<br />

regimes rely heavily on the attraction of place (i.e.,<br />

good investment site) and active popular support.<br />

The more attractive an area is to business, the<br />

more leverage the city has in extracting benefits.<br />

Similarly, the more active the public is, the more<br />

power the elected officials have in monitoring the<br />

activities of business. These two requirements,<br />

being an attractive site for investment and having<br />

active public support, render middle-class progressive<br />

regimes in the minority.<br />

The most complex of the regime types is the<br />

lower-class opportunity expansion regime. Such a<br />

regime is committed to a redistribution of resources<br />

for purposes of improving education, developing<br />

the human capital of its citizens, and expanding<br />

local business and homeownership opportunities.<br />

The coordination function in such a regime includes<br />

significant regulation of private-sector behavior.<br />

Unlike the case with middle-class progressive<br />

regimes, the <strong>cities</strong> most in need of lower-class<br />

opportunity expansion regimes are often unattractive<br />

sites for investment, and elected officials cannot<br />

engineer the kind of mass mobilization necessary to<br />

keep them in office and to take advantage of the<br />

opportunities if and when they are provided. As<br />

desirable and necessary as this regime is, it<br />

remains, as Stone suggests, “largely hypothetical.”<br />

Consequently, much still remains to be researched.<br />

Although the development and continued refinements<br />

of regime theory have advanced our understandings<br />

of governance and policy making at the<br />

local level, the nuances of power and coalition<br />

building provide ripe avenues for additional<br />

research into the workings of local government.<br />

Barbara Ferman<br />

See also Governance; Growth Machine; Local<br />

Government; Public–Private Partnerships; Urban<br />

Politics<br />

Further Readings<br />

Elkin, Stephen. 1985. “Twentieth-century Urban<br />

Regimes.” Journal of Urban Affairs 7(2):11–27.<br />

Ferman, Barbara. 1996. Challenging the Growth<br />

Machine: Neighborhood Politics in Chicago and<br />

Pittsburgh. Lawrence: University of Kansas Press.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!