13.12.2012 Views

ancient cities

ancient cities

ancient cities

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

610 Progressive City<br />

for a site; advantages maintained and enhanced<br />

through investments; magnetic attractions for businesses,<br />

services, and people (called a cumulative<br />

effect); and disproportionate growth. These factors<br />

increase the potential for a primate city to emerge.<br />

To measure primacy throughout a country’s<br />

system of <strong>cities</strong>, researchers use the rank­size rule,<br />

which captures the relationship between the ranks<br />

of <strong>cities</strong> and their populations. It was advanced by<br />

George Zipf in 1949 and builds on Mark Jefferson’s<br />

observation. Zipf asserted that “if all the settlements<br />

of a country are ranked according to population<br />

size, the sizes of the settlements will be<br />

inversely proportional to their rank”; that is, the<br />

second­largest city will be half the size of the first,<br />

the third­largest one­third the size, and so forth.<br />

The formula he used to represent this is [Pn =<br />

P1/n], where Pn is the population of nth­ranked<br />

city, P1 is the population of the largest city, and n<br />

is the rank of nth city. Zipf further developed this<br />

as a general formula [Pn = P1/n q ] where q is an<br />

adjustment factor that is different for every country<br />

because different countries have different<br />

degrees of primacy. The stronger the primacy of<br />

that country, the bigger the q value. When the largest<br />

city of a country has more than twice the population<br />

of the second­largest city, when q is greater<br />

than 1, that country is considered to have a primate<br />

urban system.<br />

See also Megalopolis; Urban Agglomeration<br />

Further Readings<br />

Eun Jin Jung<br />

Berry, B. J. L. 1961. “City Size Distribution and<br />

Economic Development.” Economic Development and<br />

Cultural Change 9(4):573–88.<br />

Jefferson, M. 1939. “The Law of the Primate City.”<br />

Geographical Review 29(2):226–32.<br />

Zipf, G. K. 1949. Human Behavior and the Principle of<br />

Least Effort. Cambridge, MA: Addison­Wesley.<br />

Pr o g r e s s i v e ci t y<br />

Gaining prominence in the United States during<br />

the final decades of the twentieth century, the term<br />

progressive city refers to an urban political and<br />

developmental strategy that emphasizes public<br />

planning, social equity, and neighborhood participation.<br />

Such an approach is often counterposed to<br />

downtown­oriented growth strategies that accentuate<br />

market­led development and that restrict the<br />

role of the public sector to tax incentives and the<br />

provision of basic services. In progressive <strong>cities</strong>,<br />

municipal governments pursue a more ambitious<br />

agenda—from public ownership and fair taxation<br />

to land use regulation and community development<br />

partnerships—to promote rational economic<br />

development, distribute the benefits of growth<br />

more widely, and involve a broader range of constituents<br />

in urban governance.<br />

Principles and Characteristics<br />

The urban progressives of the late twentieth century<br />

did not explicitly derive their principles from<br />

the reformers of the Progressive era. Yet, the<br />

political impulses of the two projects were similar.<br />

Just as the earlier movement had sought to build<br />

cross­class reconciliation and public institutions to<br />

harness the destabilizing energies of unbridled<br />

capitalist development (and thereby also offer a<br />

political alternative to corporate plutocracy and<br />

labor radicalism alike), late­twentieth­century<br />

visions of the progressive city searched for a middle<br />

ground between the stark alternatives offered<br />

by Marxist urbanism (capitalist versus socialist<br />

city) and laissez­faire capitalism (entrepreneurial<br />

versus welfare city). Articulating a set of governance<br />

principles that balanced private­ and publicsector<br />

interests, growth and equity, efficiency and<br />

reform, these conceptions of the progressive city<br />

also repositioned the urban planner in an important<br />

yet intermediary role. Neither the elite technical<br />

expert associated with postwar urban renewal<br />

nor the activist planner borne aloft by the populist<br />

energies of the 1960s movements, the progressive<br />

planner was now seen as an inventive but pragmatic<br />

professional who sought to balance economic<br />

imperatives, social equity, and the public<br />

interest.<br />

This notion of the progressive city achieved its<br />

fullest empirical development in the work of Pierre<br />

Clavel. Like many observers of U.S. <strong>cities</strong>, Clavel<br />

argued that the post–World War II political coalitions<br />

that once had united developers, construction

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!