23.07.2013 Views

samlet årgang - Økonomisk Institut - Københavns Universitet

samlet årgang - Økonomisk Institut - Københavns Universitet

samlet årgang - Økonomisk Institut - Københavns Universitet

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

316<br />

ters, and a comprehensive coverage of all the<br />

topics which one would expect to find in a<br />

complete macroeconomics course.<br />

The sub-title indicates the organisation of<br />

the book. It is divided into two halves. Book 1<br />

deals with »The Long Run«, and consists of 9<br />

chapters on growth and 3 on structural unemployment,<br />

while Book 2 deals with »The<br />

Short Run« and consists of 9 chapters on the<br />

closed economy and 4 on the open economy.<br />

The inclusion of structural unemployment<br />

alongside growth as part of »The Long Run«<br />

should help students to appreciate better this<br />

fundamental division within macroeconomics,<br />

something which is not clear to many<br />

undergraduates: that is, the division between<br />

models which are concerned with trends<br />

rather than cycles and in which only real<br />

factors matter, and models which are concerned<br />

with fluctuations about the trend and in<br />

which monetary factors and nominal rigidities<br />

play a key role. Nevertheless, the fact that it is<br />

possible to devote as much as half the book to<br />

»The Long Run« is a sign of how important<br />

the subject of growth has become in contemporary<br />

macroeconomics. Not long ago<br />

growth would quite commonly have been the<br />

last chapter out of 10 in an undergraduate<br />

macro text. In SWJ growth not only comes<br />

first (the new orthodoxy in macro textbook<br />

layout), but also takes up more than one third<br />

of the book.<br />

Another distinctive feature of SWJ’s<br />

approach is the attempt to cover all the usual<br />

topics in macroeconomics using a minimum<br />

number of different models. It is true that<br />

macroeconomics, to a much greater extent<br />

than microeconomics, often appears to students<br />

to consist of a huge variety of models,<br />

each using specialised assumptions in order<br />

to address the issue at hand, with no apparent<br />

consistency of approach. This makes it hard<br />

for students to understand how the different<br />

models and issues are related. SWJ aim to<br />

overcome this by using as few models as possible<br />

and by preserving the maximum number<br />

of common elements between them. Of<br />

course, there are underlying reasons for this<br />

NATIONALØKONOMISK TIDSSKRIFT 2005. NR. 2<br />

tendency to variety which relate to the nature<br />

of macroeconomics as a subject. It is not just<br />

due to self-indulgence or intellectual untidiness<br />

on the part of macroeconomists. Macroeconomics<br />

by definition has to deal with the<br />

whole economy – with a general equilibrium<br />

system – so that macroeconomists have in<br />

principle to model more of the economy than<br />

microeconomists. There are certain elements<br />

which they cannot leave out or else their<br />

models would be mere partial equilibrium<br />

models. This extra burden means that sacrifices<br />

have to be made somewhere in order for<br />

the analysis not to be overwhelmed by complexity.<br />

It hence results in shortcuts being<br />

taken with parts of the model, with different<br />

shortcuts being adopted depending on the<br />

particular macroeconomic phenomenon one<br />

is trying to study. It is largely from this that<br />

the »non-nested« nature of so many macromodels<br />

stems. The potential cost, then, of<br />

trying to achieve model consistency across<br />

different topics is that the model may become<br />

unnecessarily cumbersome for the modelling<br />

task in hand.<br />

Do SWJ avoid this cost? The answer is<br />

that they make a very good attempt to avoid<br />

it. As a test of how well they succeed, consider<br />

their treatment of the AD-AS model.<br />

Some version of AD-AS lies at the heart of<br />

most undergraduate macroeconomics texts.<br />

For their baseline model, SWJ choose a setup<br />

in which short-run nominal rigidity arises<br />

from money wages being set one period in advance.<br />

Inflation expectations, on which wage<br />

setting is based, are modelled as »static«: that<br />

is, equal to the lagged value of actual inflation<br />

(at least, in the closed economy; SWJ use a<br />

slightly different assumption in the open economy).<br />

Such a choice means that the majority<br />

of the short-run analysis is therefore based on<br />

»backward-looking«, »non-rational«, expectations.<br />

It further means that – since SWJ<br />

analyse the dynamic implications of all<br />

their models thoroughly – the dynamics (of<br />

the closed-economy model, anyway) are<br />

completely driven by the static expections<br />

assumption. Possibly rather too much there-

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!