23.07.2013 Views

samlet årgang - Økonomisk Institut - Københavns Universitet

samlet årgang - Økonomisk Institut - Københavns Universitet

samlet årgang - Økonomisk Institut - Københavns Universitet

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

LABOR SUPPLY BEHAVIOR AND THE DESIGN OF TAX AND TRANSFER POLICY 343<br />

Percentage points<br />

14<br />

12<br />

10<br />

8<br />

6<br />

4<br />

2<br />

0<br />

1966 1990 1993 2001<br />

Reform year<br />

Figure 7. Reform-induced reductions in tax rates.<br />

Source: Eissa et al. (2004).<br />

Marginal tax<br />

Participation tax<br />

ticipation. For this reform, the intensive welfare effect is around zero because negative<br />

effects in the phase-out region cancel out positive effects in the phase-in region of the<br />

EITC. For the 1993 reform, the large welfare gain is a result of the extensive margin<br />

strongly dominating welfare losses created on the intensive margin. Finally, for the<br />

recently enacted 2001 reform, the difference between the intensive and extensive welfare<br />

effects is less pronounced. This occurs for two reasons: First, the 2001 tax cuts<br />

reduced participation tax rates only slightly and, second, by the year 2000 the previous<br />

reforms had already eliminated much of the inefficiency along the extensive margin. 16<br />

Our finding that extensive responses drive almost all of the welfare effects created<br />

by the four reforms underpins the importance of accounting for this margin of labor<br />

supply. A simulation based on the traditional, convex labor supply model with only<br />

intensive responses would seriously underestimate the welfare effects. For the 1993<br />

reform, even the sign would be wrong. Here, the intensive welfare effect in our base-<br />

16. One might argue that our findings regarding the relative sizes of the extensive and intensive welfare<br />

effects were to be expected under the assumed elasticity scenario. Notice, however, that the difference between<br />

extensive and intensive welfare effects cannot be explained exclusively by elasticities, since the two<br />

kinds of welfare effects are related in different ways to the tax-transfer system. For example, for the tax act<br />

of 1990, increasing the hours-of-work elasticity would leave the intensive welfare effect more or less<br />

unchanged since the losses in the phase-out region would continue to cancel out the gains created in the<br />

phase-in region. For the 1993 reform, increasing the intensive elasticity would simply exacerbate the welfare<br />

loss along that margin, thereby reinforcing the point regarding the difference of welfare effects along<br />

the two margins.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!