23.07.2013 Views

samlet årgang - Økonomisk Institut - Københavns Universitet

samlet årgang - Økonomisk Institut - Københavns Universitet

samlet årgang - Økonomisk Institut - Københavns Universitet

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

342<br />

Percent<br />

60<br />

50<br />

40<br />

30<br />

20<br />

10<br />

0<br />

1966 1990 1993 2001<br />

Reform year<br />

Figure 6a. Marginal tax rate.<br />

Source. Elssa et al. (2004).<br />

Excl. benefits<br />

Incl. benefits<br />

NATIONALØKONOMISK TIDSSKRIFT 2005. NR. 3<br />

Percent<br />

60<br />

Excl. benefits<br />

50<br />

40<br />

30<br />

20<br />

10<br />

0<br />

Incl. benefits<br />

-10 1966 1990 1993 2001<br />

Reform year<br />

Figure 6b. Participation tax rate.<br />

Source. Elssa et al. (2004).<br />

levels over the period, and they also incorporate any behavioral responses to these<br />

tax and benefit changes along with macro/time effects on income and demographic<br />

variables. To isolate the direct impact of federal tax reforms, we calculate the changes<br />

in the tax rates that are attributed to the reforms alone. The results are illustrated in<br />

Figure 7, which confirms that the decrease in effective tax rates over the 15-year period<br />

has been driven to a large extent, by tax changes at the federal level. This was particularly<br />

the case for the 1986 and 1993 reforms, which reduced the participation tax rate by 8<br />

and 13 percentage points, respectively.<br />

There is a substantial variation in wage income and tax rates across the single<br />

mothers in the data. This heterogeneity highlights the need for using micro-simulations<br />

to evaluate the tax reforms. Large errors may occur in more aggregate studies because<br />

of the correlation between earnings, tax rates and tax changes. In Eissa, Kleven<br />

and Kreiner (2004), we carry out a number of simulations assuming different elasticity<br />

scenarios. The simulations point to substantial welfare gains for all the reforms. In<br />

particular, this is the case for the tax reform act of 1986. In our baseline scenario with<br />

a participation elasticity equal to 0.4 and a (compensated) hours-of-work elasticity<br />

equal to 0.1, we obtain a welfare gain for this reform equal to 7.3 percent of labor<br />

income. 15 The welfare effects are also high for the 1993 reform (2.3 percent of labor<br />

income), which contained the single largest expansion of the EITC. For the 1990 and<br />

2001 reforms, the welfare gains are not quite as large.<br />

For all four reforms, most of the total welfare gain is generated on the extensive<br />

margin. While 3 /4 of the gain from the 1986 tax act is created by labor market entry,<br />

essentially all of the positive effect from the 1990 reform is driven by labor force par-<br />

For this reform, it is interesting to note that a total labor supply elasticity of 0.6 – certainly not out of bound<br />

of the empirical estimates – would imply Laffer curve effects. In this scenario, the large tax reductions granted<br />

to single mothers are recouped entirely from the labor supply responses created by the reform.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!