23.07.2013 Views

samlet årgang - Økonomisk Institut - Københavns Universitet

samlet årgang - Økonomisk Institut - Københavns Universitet

samlet årgang - Økonomisk Institut - Københavns Universitet

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

LABOR SUPPLY BEHAVIOR AND THE DESIGN OF TAX AND TRANSFER POLICY 325<br />

Like the EITC, this program was designed to induce low-income people with children,<br />

typically single mothers, from welfare into work. Their results indicate that the reform<br />

was quite effective in achieving this goal, increasing the participation rate of single<br />

women with children by 2.2 percentage points (5 percent).<br />

While the literature on labor supply in Anglo-Saxon countries is extensive, there are<br />

fewer studies for continental European and Scandinavian countries. One might expect<br />

that labor supply elasticities are smaller in the more rigid labor markets of continental<br />

Europe and Scandinavia. However, several recent studies suggest that this is not the<br />

case. A number of structural studies of female labor supply are surveyed in Blundell<br />

and MaCurdy (1999). These studies found high elasticities – typically between 0.5 and<br />

1 – across a number of European countries such as Germany, the Netherlands, France,<br />

Italy, Sweden, and the UK. 1 Since these results were based on samples containing nonemployed<br />

individuals, the participation response is included in the estimated elasticities.<br />

Indeed, the results probably reflect an underlying labor supply curve where elasticities<br />

are large around the point of participation but fall off rapidly with increases in working<br />

hours, Blundell (1995).<br />

The finding that tax incentives may have substantial effects on labor force participation<br />

is consistent with another stream of empirical literature estimating the effect of<br />

out-of-work benefits on unemployment. Krueger and Meyer (2002) surveys the evidence<br />

from a number of OECD countries. They conclude that benefits raise the incidence<br />

and the duration of unemployment, and that the elasticity of lost work time<br />

with respect to benefits tends to be around one. Since the risk of unemployment is largest<br />

among low-skilled workers, this evidence also indicates that strong participation<br />

responses tend to be concentrated at the bottom of the wage distribution.<br />

2.2 Modeling entry-exit behavior in the labor market<br />

Having established that extensive labor supply responses are empirically important,<br />

we wish to explore their implications for the welfare evaluation of tax and transfer<br />

policy. In order to do so, we have to think about how to model participation behavior.<br />

As emphasized by Eissa et al. (2004), a realistic model must be consistent with empirical<br />

distributions of hours worked showing almost no workers at low annual or weekly<br />

hours of work. In other words, if individuals decide to work at all, they tend to work<br />

a substantial number of hours (say, 30 or 40 hours per week). To explain this discreteness<br />

of participation behavior, we need a framework featuring non-convexities in<br />

1. We are not aware of studies estimating the elasticity of labor force participation with respect to taxes for<br />

Denmark. While the results for Sweden may give some indication of labor supply behavior in Denmark, it<br />

would be interesting and important to carry out econometric studies based on Danish data and reforms in order<br />

to discuss the design of future tax and welfare reforms in this country.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!