23.07.2013 Views

samlet årgang - Økonomisk Institut - Københavns Universitet

samlet årgang - Økonomisk Institut - Københavns Universitet

samlet årgang - Økonomisk Institut - Københavns Universitet

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

444<br />

NATIONALØKONOMISK TIDSSKRIFT 2005. NR. 3<br />

dr e 1 2 1 re 1 2 13 r e 1<br />

= v 1 (c 2 13 –1)+v 2 (c 13 c 23 – c 12 ) – (37)<br />

dt i 1 2 3 (1 – t) 2<br />

dr e 2 2 2 re 2 1 23 r e 2<br />

= v 2 (c 2 23 –1)+v 1 (c 13 c 23 – c 12 ) – (38)<br />

dt i 2 2 3 (1 – t) 2<br />

These results show that even if investors are well-diversified (v1→ 0 and v2→ 0),<br />

the shareholder income tax will distort the required return to unquoted shares. In the<br />

normal case where j 3 > 0, a higher shareholder income tax rate is seen to reduce the<br />

cost of equity finance for unquoted companies, because the tax falls more heavily on<br />

quoted shares, thereby inducing substitution towards unquoted shares.<br />

In summary, the Swedish policy of granting double tax relief only to holders of<br />

unquoted shares is not neutral towards real investment incentives. To achieve (approximate)<br />

neutrality in the case of well-diversified investors, it is necessary to grant a<br />

general rate-of-return allowance for all shareholdings, as we saw in section 4. Alternatively,<br />

neutrality with well-diversified investors can be achieved if the shareholder income<br />

tax with a rate-of-return allowance is levied only on returns to unquoted shares<br />

while returns to quoted shares are left free of tax, as proposed in Sørensen (2005b). In<br />

such a regime one can show that dre 1 /dt and dre 2 /dt will again be given by (31) and (32),<br />

implying dre j /dt → 0 for vj → 0, j = 1, 2. Imposing the tax only on unquoted shares<br />

might make sense if the main purpose of the tax is to prevent the owners of small companies<br />

from transforming heavily taxed management salaries into lightly-taxed dividends<br />

or capital gains on shares, and if policy makers do not wish to give domestic<br />

shareholders a tax incentive to sell their shares in quoted companies to foreign investors.<br />

Assuming plausibly that 13 > 0 and 23 > 0, a comparison of (31) and (32) to (37)<br />

and (38) reveals that the current Swedish tax system provides a stronger stimulus to<br />

risk-taking in small companies compared to a general shareholder income tax with a<br />

rate-of-return allowance for all shares (»the uniform tax«), or compared to a tax which<br />

is levied only on the equity premium on unquoted shares (»the selective tax«). The fact<br />

that the Swedish tax system tends to reduce the cost of capital for small companies<br />

even when investors are fully diversified suggests that it is too favourable to investment<br />

in this sector. By contrast, »the uniform tax« and »the selective tax« will only<br />

tend to stimulate risk-taking in unquoted companies when investors are not well diversified,<br />

indicating that these tax systems have better efficiency properties than the<br />

current Swedish rules.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!