23.07.2013 Views

samlet årgang - Økonomisk Institut - Københavns Universitet

samlet årgang - Økonomisk Institut - Københavns Universitet

samlet årgang - Økonomisk Institut - Københavns Universitet

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

434<br />

NATIONALØKONOMISK TIDSSKRIFT 2005. NR. 3<br />

From 2006 Norway will only impose personal tax on dividends exceeding an imputed<br />

rate of return to the share, and Sweden has already implemented a similar tax rule for<br />

dividends from unquoted shares. Several other countries are granting full or partial<br />

credit for the underlying corporation tax against the personal tax on dividends.<br />

However, proponents of the »new view« of dividend taxation have argued that there<br />

is little need to alleviate the double taxation of dividends. They point out that retained<br />

earnings are the main source of equity finance, and that the returns to shareholders<br />

accrue as capital gains when corporate investment is financed by retentions. Hence<br />

they conclude that double taxation is hardly a serious problem in a world where effective<br />

tax rates on capital gains on shares are typically quite low, see King (1974), Auerbach<br />

(1979), Bradford (1981), and Sinn (1987).<br />

More recently, the international integration of capital markets has popularized the<br />

view that neither personal dividend taxes nor personal taxes on capital gains have any<br />

significant impact on corporate investment incentives in a small open economy, see,<br />

e.g., Boadway and Bruce (1992), Sørensen (1995), Andersson et al. (1998), and Fuest<br />

and Huber (2000). According to this view the marginal shareholder in a small economy<br />

with an open stock market is likely to be a foreign investor whose required return<br />

on shares is unaffected by personal taxes on domestic residents. If a residence-based<br />

personal tax on equity income makes shareholding less attractive to domestic investors,<br />

they will sell off (some of) their domestic shares to foreign investors who<br />

stand ready to buy domestic shares at prices determined on the world stock market.<br />

Thus, although they will influence the pattern of ownership, personal taxes on equity<br />

income will have no effect on the cost of equity finance for domestic corporations.<br />

Many policy makers have found it hard to accept the postulate that personal taxes<br />

on equity income are irrelevant for real investment incentives in a small open economy.<br />

They argue that although this claim may be relevant for large firms that are<br />

listed on the stock exchange, the smaller unquoted firms do not, in practice, have access<br />

to the international equity market. If shares in small unquoted companies are imperfect<br />

substitutes for shares in large public corporations, say, because they have different risk<br />

characteristics, one might therefore think that personal taxes on dividends and capital<br />

gains will drive up the cost of equity for small companies.<br />

In a recent paper Apel and Södersten (1999) have tried to take this concern seriously.<br />

They set up a mean-variance model of portfolio choice in a small open economy where<br />

domestic investors may hold three assets: risk-free bonds; shares in small companies<br />

which are not traded internationally; and shares in large corporations which are traded<br />

in the international stock market. Within this framework they study the effects of personal<br />

taxes on domestic holdings of traded shares and on the required rate of return on<br />

non-traded shares. Their most striking result is that, for plausible parameter values,

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!