23.07.2013 Views

samlet årgang - Økonomisk Institut - Københavns Universitet

samlet årgang - Økonomisk Institut - Københavns Universitet

samlet årgang - Økonomisk Institut - Københavns Universitet

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

332<br />

Income gain from entry<br />

T+B<br />

Y<br />

Y-T-B<br />

CS<br />

Government revenue<br />

GR<br />

DWL<br />

E B<br />

B<br />

←<br />

Labor<br />

supply<br />

Deadweight Loss<br />

Consumer surplus<br />

Employed<br />

individuals<br />

Figure 4a: Welfare cost of taxation with<br />

extensive labor supply responses.<br />

E A<br />

NATIONALØKONOMISK TIDSSKRIFT 2005. NR. 3<br />

Income gain from entry<br />

Behavioral effect<br />

Labor<br />

supply<br />

Mechanical effect<br />

Employed<br />

individuals<br />

Figure 4b: Marginal welfare cost of<br />

taxation with extensive labor supply responses.<br />

participate, and small changes in labor market incentives will typically create small<br />

adjustments in the number of employed workers. The combination of non-convexities<br />

and heterogeneity enables us to explain discrete entry-exit behavior at the individual<br />

level together with smooth changes in employment at the macro level. Here we present<br />

a very simple framework, which illuminates the main insights. A more general analysis<br />

is presented in Eissa et al. (2004).<br />

Consider a group of individuals who all have the same hourly productivity/wage w.<br />

For simplification, we disregard intensive labor supply responses and assume that all<br />

individuals work some fixed number of hours, ¯ h, if they work at all. Those who are<br />

working receive the same pre-tax earnings denoted by Y w ¯ h. The individuals face<br />

fixed work costs, which may reflect monetary costs, time costs or simply a fixed disutility<br />

of working. These work costs are assumed to vary (smoothly) across individuals,<br />

thereby giving rise to the upward sloping labor supply curve in Figure 4a. This curve<br />

displays the number of employed individuals as a function of the net income gain of<br />

working (i.e., earnings net of taxes paid and transfers lost). At a low net income gain,<br />

many individuals stay outside the labor market because their work costs outweigh the<br />

gain from entry. As the net income gain increases, more and more individuals find it<br />

worthwhile to enter the labor market so as to generate a positively sloped extensive<br />

labor supply curve.<br />

With no tax-transfer system, the equilibrium would be at point A. Assume now that<br />

an employed who is earning Y has to pay an amount T in taxes (net of any benefits),<br />

while a non-employed individual receives the amount B in welfare benefits (net of<br />

any taxes). This implies that the net income gain of working equals Y – T – B, thereby<br />

T+B<br />

Y<br />

Y-T-B<br />

CS<br />

GR<br />

B<br />

C<br />

DWL

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!