23.07.2013 Views

samlet årgang - Økonomisk Institut - Københavns Universitet

samlet årgang - Økonomisk Institut - Københavns Universitet

samlet årgang - Økonomisk Institut - Københavns Universitet

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

LABOR SUPPLY BEHAVIOR AND THE DESIGN OF TAX AND TRANSFER POLICY 337<br />

tively, taxable income can respond if higher taxes lead to a more aggressive interpretation<br />

of tax rules (e.g., claiming questionable deductions) or tax evasion (understating<br />

income, claiming unjustified deductions). Tax-induced changes in avoidance or evasion<br />

affect government revenue, hence creating efficiency losses in the same way that labor<br />

supply responses do.<br />

This type of reasoning underlies the recent literature on the elasticity of taxable income,<br />

starting with the important paper by Feldstein (1995). While taxation may affect<br />

behavior in a myriad of ways – as suggested by the above comments – the responses<br />

matter for efficiency only to the extent that they change taxable income. While it may be<br />

extremely difficult to estimate each of the responses separately, it is possible to estimate<br />

the elasticity of taxable income based data from individual tax returns. A focus on this<br />

parameter might make intensive responses more important than portrayed in our review<br />

of the empirical labor supply literature.<br />

Indeed, for the United States, the literature has shown that the (intensive) elasticity<br />

of taxable income can be very high at the top of the income distribution (see Saez,<br />

2004 for a recent survey). However, this is a phenomenon occurring only at the extreme<br />

top of the income distribution (top 1%). We are not aware of studies estimating the elasticity<br />

of taxable income for European countries.<br />

Finally, based on the discussion in this section, one might be tempted to conclude<br />

that we do not need to distinguish between different margins of behavioral response.<br />

To estimate the revenue (and hence efficiency) effects, it seems that all we need to<br />

know is the elasticity of taxable income and then apply a marginal tax wedge. However,<br />

this is not entirely correct. An obvious point is that the tax system may involve<br />

several different bases subject to selective tax rates. In this case, different margins of<br />

response can relate to different bases and tax rates, and we then have to distinguish<br />

between different taxable income elasticities to get the revenue and efficiency effects<br />

right. A more subtle point is that, under non-linear tax systems, marginal and discrete<br />

changes in taxable income are taxed differently. As shown in the previous sections on<br />

intensive and extensive labor supply effects, it is important to distinguish between<br />

marginal and discrete effects in the measurement of excess burden. Hence, the discussion<br />

in this section is entirely consistent with the previous conclusions.<br />

4. The evaluation of tax and transfer reforms<br />

Following Harberger (1964), a large numerical literature has attempted to evaluate<br />

the distortions to the labor-leisure choice induced by labor income taxation and the<br />

impact of different tax reforms. The evaluation methods include simple deadweight<br />

loss calculations, Browning (1987, 1995), Computable General Equilibrium models,<br />

Ballard et al., (1985); Ballard (1988), and micro-simulations, Browning and Johnson,

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!