23.07.2013 Views

samlet årgang - Økonomisk Institut - Københavns Universitet

samlet årgang - Økonomisk Institut - Københavns Universitet

samlet årgang - Økonomisk Institut - Københavns Universitet

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

352<br />

NATIONALØKONOMISK TIDSSKRIFT 2005. NR. 3<br />

nothing for the rich to give money to the working poor – implying that the reform is<br />

(almost) Pareto improving. For a number of other countries, the working poor policy<br />

creates very small efficiency losses such that the trade-off is quite close to one. This<br />

applies to countries such as Austria, Greece, Luxembourg, the Netherlands, and<br />

United Kingdom. In these countries there is no significant trade-off between efficiency<br />

and equality when we consider redistribution from the rich to the working poor.<br />

Only in the case of Finland and Sweden does the working poor policy involve an unfavorable<br />

equity-efficiency trade-off, which reflects in part the extremely equal earnings<br />

distribution in these two countries.<br />

A comparison of Table 1 and 2 reveals that countries with relatively high participation<br />

tax rates at the bottom of the earnings distribution, such as Denmark, Ireland<br />

and France, tend to gain more by choosing a working poor policy rather than a traditional<br />

welfare policy. The working poor policy creates higher incentives for participation<br />

in the labor force. Moreover, participation increases mainly at the bottom deciles<br />

where participation elasticities are large. If participation tax rates are very large at<br />

the bottom deciles, the increase in labor market participation creates a large increase<br />

in government revenue (through reduced benefit expenditures and a higher tax take)<br />

and hence in economic efficiency.<br />

Ceteris paribus, the presence of a highly equal pre-tax earnings distribution tends to<br />

make redistribution very costly. This applies to redistributional policies in general, and<br />

to the working poor policy in particular because it attempts to redistribute only within<br />

the group of workers who are more equal than the entire population of workers and<br />

non-workers. The presence of strongly compressed wage distributions in Scandinavian<br />

countries (cf. Table 1) is often mentioned as an argument against pursuing in-work<br />

benefit reforms in this region. It is therefore interesting that the working poor policy<br />

seems to be extremely desirable in Denmark, more so than in any other country. The<br />

explanation is that participation tax rates are very high in Denmark, especially in the<br />

bottom deciles where participation elasticities are also high. In the simulations, this effect<br />

strongly dominates the effect of a compressed earnings distribution. On the other<br />

hand, the working poor policy is less desirable in Finland and Sweden, because participation<br />

tax rates at the bottom are somewhat lower there and because the earnings<br />

distribution is even more equal than in Denmark. It is important to realize, however,<br />

that the equity-efficiency trade-off is even worse for the traditional welfare policy in<br />

Finland and Sweden. The bottom line is that both kinds of redistribution are very costly<br />

in these two countries, at least on the margin, due to the combination of an already<br />

equal distribution and high tax rates.<br />

Besides the presence of an equal earnings distribution, a potential argument against<br />

working poor policies in Scandinavia is that participation elasticities might be signifi-

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!