23.07.2013 Views

samlet årgang - Økonomisk Institut - Københavns Universitet

samlet årgang - Økonomisk Institut - Københavns Universitet

samlet årgang - Økonomisk Institut - Københavns Universitet

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

LABOR SUPPLY BEHAVIOR AND THE DESIGN OF TAX AND TRANSFER POLICY 331<br />

that the welfare loss is given by the revenue loss created by changed behavior, is not<br />

related to the specific model adopted here but holds in general for tax policy analysis.<br />

For empirical applications, it is useful to rewrite the above result. Let denote the<br />

elasticity of hours worked with respect to the net-of-tax wage rate. 7 Then the change in<br />

the deadweight loss in proportion to the aggregate wage income may be written as<br />

DWL m<br />

– · · m (3)<br />

wh 1 –m<br />

This expression is a classic Harberger-type formula for the marginal deadweight<br />

burden of taxation. 8 It shows that the marginal welfare cost depends on the initial level<br />

of the marginal tax rate, the increase in the marginal tax rate, and the hours-of-work<br />

elasticity. Notice that the marginal loss is equal to zero when the marginal tax rate is<br />

zero. That is, initially the welfare cost of raising tax revenue is zero. As the tax rate is<br />

increased, the marginal welfare cost of taxation also increases at a given labor supply<br />

elasticity. In other words, it becomes more and more costly to raise additional government<br />

revenue as the tax rate goes up. In fact, welfare effects can be substantial even for<br />

very small labor supply elasticities provided that initial marginal tax rates are high.<br />

Finally, since the empirical evidence does not give any indication of large, significant<br />

differences in hours-of-work responses across individuals (conditional on labor force<br />

participation), we may conclude that the largest efficiency gains of tax rate reductions<br />

are to be found where marginal tax rates are relatively high.<br />

3.2 The excess burden of taxation with extensive labor supply responses<br />

The modeling of tax distortions along the extensive margin is a bit more complicated.<br />

As noted in Section 2, an appropriate theory requires some type of non-convexity<br />

in order to account for the observed discreteness in labor supply behavior. 9<br />

In addition, the theory has to incorporate heterogeneity across individuals. With no<br />

heterogeneity in preferences or productivity, either everybody participates or nobody<br />

participates in the labor market. In reality, some fraction of those in their working age<br />

7. To be precise, is the compensated hours-of-work elasticity. As described in footnote 3, income effects<br />

are irrelevant for the measurement of the excess burden of taxation.<br />

8. The result is more general than it appears. Specifically, the result is not restricted to a proportional tax<br />

scheme although this is the case for Figure 3a, b and for expression (1). The relationship in (3) holds for any<br />

tax system as long as the marginal tax rate is locally constant. The result also holds for other definitions of<br />

the deadweight loss. Here, we have derived expression (3) from a simple Marshalian definition but the<br />

result may also be derived from deadweight loss measures based on compensating variation, equivalent<br />

variation, or compensating surplus.<br />

9. A general framework for analyzing welfare effects with discrete choice is provided by Small and Rosen<br />

(1981).

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!