15.06.2013 Views

inostrani kapital kao faktor razvoja zemalja - Ekonomski fakultet u ...

inostrani kapital kao faktor razvoja zemalja - Ekonomski fakultet u ...

inostrani kapital kao faktor razvoja zemalja - Ekonomski fakultet u ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

4. Is there a scope for Developmental States<br />

in Central and Eastern Europe?<br />

What is the lesson of this short recollection of events for transition<br />

economies? A number of changes of the previous picture are due here. First of all<br />

there is no tradition of Developmental States in CEE. Economic planning was not<br />

conceived for export-led industrial growth, but rather had a clear ideological<br />

connotation. If a social pact was in place at all, between the State and the<br />

population, it was between a ‘less unequal distribution of income’ (compared to the<br />

West) and a less demanding work discipline and factor efficiency (which translated<br />

de facto in less output). But returning to our issue, what kind of institutional<br />

building can we suggest for transition economies, to promote industrial<br />

development, as a result of capital liberalization? To answer this question I suggest<br />

we concentrate on how to produce a better coordination within each column of<br />

Figure 1, by reading it from right to left.<br />

4.1 Performance<br />

Contrary to East Asian economies, the CEECs have not developed en exportled<br />

model of development, based on the acquisition of external money and finance<br />

from systematic foreign trade surpluses. On the contrary, the general position of the<br />

current account balance is almost everywhere in the negative, and almost all capital<br />

inflows are foreign owned, rather than domestically generated by excess exports.<br />

Yet, a number of studies on the reasons why FDI did flow into the CEECs after<br />

transition found that the lower labor costs per unit of production were the main<br />

motivation, followed by market penetration. So, a relative cost advantage for labor<br />

intensive productions was there in the first place. But as we all know, there was<br />

little domestic accumulation of money and international reserves, in the CEECs,<br />

both for the severity of the economic crisis, all along the 90ies, and the necessity to<br />

turn the old existing capital and organization into the new ‘market framework’.<br />

Besides, the rapid accumulation of wealth that took place in some cases, only<br />

partially translated into legal domestic investments, and took the usual route of<br />

capital exports. So the engine of growth, in the corresponding column, had to relay,<br />

to a great extent, on foreign capital, especially FDI, for accumulation and<br />

productivity gains, with a premium to foreigners in the allocation of resources, as<br />

capital was scarce to begin with.<br />

Yet the FDI motivation of ‘market penetration’ has gained momentum, in<br />

recent times, to the extent that wages grow faster than productivity, and domestic<br />

demand starts to take off. Furthermore a strong increase in the intra-industry trade<br />

between most CEECs and Western Europe took place, in the last decade. This is a<br />

clear indication that both a ‘real’ and ‘nominal’ integration is going on in Europe.<br />

‘Real’ (supply side) integration emerges when, for lack or inefficiencies of local<br />

firms, FDI are made to transfer labor-intensive phases of production into the<br />

CEECs. Intra-industry trade is thus the result of trade in semi-finished products,<br />

31

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!