05.03.2014 Views

Emissions Scenarios - IPCC

Emissions Scenarios - IPCC

Emissions Scenarios - IPCC

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Scenario Driving Forces 141<br />

growth" and "evolutionary" economic models. They have been<br />

able to demonstrate the flaws in some of the simpler solutions<br />

to technology diffusion often advocated - for example, they<br />

show how free trade might sometimes exacerbate existing gaps<br />

in institutions, skills, and technology.<br />

The complex interactions that underpin technology diffusion<br />

may give rise to regularities at an aggregate level. The<br />

geographical and spaflal distribution of successive<br />

technologies displays patterns similar to those found in the<br />

succession of biological species in ecosystems, and also in the<br />

succession of social institutions, cultures, myths, and<br />

languages. These processes have been analyzed, for example,<br />

in CampbeU (1959), Marchetfl (1980), Grübler and<br />

Nakicenovic (1991), and Grübler (1998a). An extensive review<br />

of the process of international technology diffusion is available<br />

in the <strong>IPCC</strong> Special Report on Methodological and<br />

Technological Issues in Technology Transfer (<strong>IPCC</strong>, 2000).<br />

That report provides a synthesis of the available knowledge and<br />

experience of the economic, social and institutional processes<br />

involved.<br />

Many attempts to endogenize technical change in economic<br />

models rely on a linear approach in which technical change is<br />

linked to the level of investment in R&D (e.g., Grossman and<br />

Helpman, 1991, 1993). More importantly, this linear model has<br />

been the basis of many governments' strategies for<br />

technological innovation. As mentioned above, important<br />

additional features of technological change include<br />

uncertainty, the reliance on sources of knowledge other than<br />

R&D, "leaming by doing" and other phenomena of "increasing<br />

returns" that often lead to technological "lock in" and hence<br />

great difficulties in introducing new alternatives.<br />

These features can be captured to some degree in models and a<br />

great deal of experimentation has taken place with different<br />

model specifications. However, the first feature, uncertainty,<br />

means that models cannot be used to predict the process of<br />

technical change. This uncertainty stems partly from lack of<br />

knowledge - the outcomes of cutting-edge empirical research<br />

simply cannot be predicted. It also stems from the complexity<br />

of the influences on technological change, and in particular the<br />

social and cultural influences that are extremely difficuh to<br />

describe in fomal models. Recent attempts to endogenize<br />

technical change in energy and economic models are reviewed<br />

by Azar (1996). Opfimizafion models usually treat technology<br />

development as exogenous, but technology deployment as<br />

endogenous and driven by relative technology life-cycle costs.<br />

A few GHG emission projection models (e.g., Messner, 1997)<br />

were developed to incorporate "leaming by doing" - the<br />

reduction in technology costs and improvement in performance<br />

that can result from experience (Arrow, 1962). Models have<br />

also been developed that explicifly include technological<br />

uncertainty to analyze robust technology policy options (e.g.,<br />

Grübler and Messner, 1996; Messner et al, 1996). Other<br />

models developed more recently 1псофога1е the effects of<br />

investment in knowledge and R&D (Goulder and Mathai,<br />

1998). Economists and others who study technological change<br />

have developed models that take a variety of dynamics into<br />

account (Silverberg, 1988). Some models focus on<br />

technologies themselves, for example examining the various<br />

sources of "increasing returns to scale" and "lock-in" (Arthur,<br />

1989, 1994). Other models focus on firms and other decisionmakers,<br />

and their processes of information assimilation,<br />

imitation, and leaming (Nelson and Winter, 1982; Silverberg,<br />

1988; Andersen, 1994). Few of these dynamics, apart from<br />

"increasing returns to scale," have been applied to the<br />

projection of GHG emissions from the energy sector.<br />

3.5. Agriculture and Land-Use <strong>Emissions</strong><br />

3.5.1. Introduction<br />

The most important categories of land-use emissions are CO^<br />

from net deforestation, CH^ from rice cultivation, CH^ from<br />

enteric fermentation of cattle, and N^0 from fertilizer<br />

application. These sources account for nearly all the land-use<br />

emissions of COj (Schimel et al., 1995), about 53% of the<br />

land-use emissions of CH4 (Prather, et al, 1995), and about<br />

80% of land-use emissions of Np (Prather, et ai. 1995).<br />

These estimates, however, have a high uncertainty.<br />

Measurements and analyses of other sources of CH^ and N^O<br />

(notably biomass burning, landfills, animal waste, and sewage)<br />

ai-e relatively rare, but increasing (Bogner et al., 1997, in the<br />

literature. Of the scenarios reviewed for this report (see Table<br />

3.7), about 20 address emissions from agriculture and land-use<br />

change (Lashof and Tirpak, 1990; Houghton, 1991; Leggett et<br />

al., 1992; Matsuoka and Morita, 1994; Alcamo et ai, 1998;<br />

Alcamo and Kreileman, 1996; Leemans et al, 1996).<br />

Current assessments of GHG emissions indicate that land use or<br />

land cover activities make an important contribution to the<br />

concentration of GHGs in the atmosphere;-' these are referreà to<br />

as "land-use emissions" in this report."* Of the tl-nee most<br />

important GHGs, the contribution of land-use emissions to total<br />

global COj is relatively small (23%), but it is very large for CH^<br />

(74%) and N^0. Furthermore, although land-use emissions<br />

make up only a small percentage of global COj emissions, they<br />

comprise a large part (45%) of CO^ emissions from developing<br />

countries, and an even larger percentage of their total CH^<br />

(78%) and Np (76%) emissions (Pepper et<br />

al.,1992). Hence, from a variety of perspectives, the<br />

contribution of land-use emissions to total emissions of GHGs<br />

is important, and consequently their future trends are relevant to<br />

the estimation of climate change and its mitigation.<br />

^ These activities include deforestation, afforestation, changes in<br />

agricultural management, and other anthropogenic land-use changes<br />

that result in a net flow of GHGs to or from the atmosphere. They<br />

exclude natural biogenic emissions and emissions that are not<br />

related to anthropogenic activity such as CO2 from volcanoes or<br />

volatile organic compounds from forests.<br />

We include deforestation in this category of emissions even though<br />

this is a process of land-cover change rather than a land-use activity.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!