05.03.2014 Views

Emissions Scenarios - IPCC

Emissions Scenarios - IPCC

Emissions Scenarios - IPCC

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

An Overview of <strong>Scenarios</strong> 201<br />

Figure 4-6 illustrates the evolution of final energy intensities<br />

for the four SRES marker scenarios. Instead of time, per capita<br />

income is shown on the horizontal axis, to illustrate a<br />

conditional convergence of regional final energy intensities.<br />

Invariably, intensities are projected to decline with increasing<br />

income levels. As discussed in Chapter 3, the main reason for<br />

this trettd stems from the common source of economic growth<br />

and energy intensity improvements - technological change.<br />

All else being equal, the faster intensity improvements are, the<br />

faster aggregate productivity (per capita income) grows. An<br />

important méthodologie improvement over previous studies is<br />

the explicit inclusion of non-commercial energy forms in<br />

some SRES models, drawing on estimates as reported in <strong>IPCC</strong><br />

WGII SAR (Watson et al., 1996) and in Nakicenovic et al.<br />

(1998).<br />

In the Al and ВI scenarios, per capita income differences are<br />

substantially narrowed and convergent because of increased<br />

economic integration and rapid technological change.<br />

Therefore, differences in energy intensities are also narrowed<br />

significantly and are convergent, as shown in Figure 4.6. The<br />

Bl storyline describes a development path to a less materialintensive<br />

economy. Hence, the final energy intensities in the В1<br />

marker are lowest among the four SRES marker scenarios for<br />

a given per capita income level. The A2 storyline reflects a<br />

world with less rapid technological change, as shown by the<br />

smallest rate of energy intensity improvement among the four<br />

marker scenarios.Different interpretations of the four<br />

scenario storylines, as well as alternative rates of energy<br />

intensity improvement to the four marker scenarios, are<br />

discussed below.<br />

Owing to méthodologie differences across the six models (see<br />

Box 4-7) it is not possible to disaggregate energy intensity<br />

improvements into various components, such as structural<br />

change, price effects, technological change, etc., in a consistent<br />

way. In some models (macro-economic) price effects are<br />

differentiated from "everything else" (frequently labeled AEEI,<br />

or autonomous energy intensity improvements). As a rule, the<br />

importance of non-price factors is an inverse function of the<br />

time horizon considered. Over the short-term, the impacts of<br />

economic structural change and technology diffusion are<br />

necessarily low. Hence, prices assume a paramount importance<br />

in driving altemative energy demand patterns in short-term (to<br />

2010-2020) scenario studies (e.g., lEA, 1998; EIA, 1997,<br />

1999). Over the longer term (i.e., the time horizon considered<br />

by the SRES scenarios), economic stmctural and technological<br />

changes become more pronounced, as does their influence on<br />

energy intensity improvements and energy demand. This does<br />

not imply that prices do not matter over the long term, but<br />

simply that "everything else" (e.g., AEEI) is likely to outweigh<br />

the impacts of prices, as indeed suggested by quantitative<br />

scenario analyses performed within the Energy Modeling<br />

Forum EMF-14 (Weyant, 1995).<br />

Important feedback mechanisms between technological<br />

change and costs (and thus also prices) exist over the long term.<br />

These are as a rule treated endogenously in the models, for<br />

instance when modeling long-mn resource extraction costs or<br />

structural changes in energy supply options (see Sections 4.4.6<br />

and 4.4.7). Energy prices are also strongly affected by policies<br />

(e.g., taxation), but to project these far into the future is both<br />

outside the capability of currently available methodologies and<br />

outside the general "policy neutral" stance of the SRES<br />

scenarios. Therefore, most models treat dynamic changes in<br />

(average and marginal) costs as the driving force for energy<br />

intensity improvements and for technology choice (see<br />

Sections 4.4.6 and 4.4.7).<br />

4.4.5.1. Al <strong>Scenarios</strong><br />

Improvements in energy efficiency on the demand side are<br />

assumed to be relatively low in the AIB marker scenario,<br />

because of low energy prices caused by rapid technological<br />

progress in resource availability and energy supply technologies<br />

(see Sections 4.4.6 and 4.4.7). These low energy prices provide<br />

littie incentive to improve end-use-energy efficiencies and high<br />

income levels encourage comfortable and convenient(and often<br />

energy intensive) lifestyles (especially in the household, service,<br />

and transport sectors). Efficient technologies are not fully<br />

introduced into the end-use side, dematerialization processes in<br />

the industrial sector are not well promoted, lifestyles become<br />

energy intensive, and private motor vehicles are used more in<br />

developing countries as per capita GDP increases. Conversely,<br />

fast rates of economic growth and capital turnover and rising<br />

incomes also enable the diffusion of more efficient technologies<br />

2' Note that this statement only indicates the relative position of the<br />

A2 scenario compared to other SRES scenario families. In absolute<br />

tenus the scenario's decline in energy intensity is very substantial - on<br />

average, energy use per unit of GDP declines by a factor of more than<br />

two as a result of the compounding effect of an improvement rate of<br />

final energy intensity of 0.8% per year. Comparison of this<br />

improvement rate with the SRES scenario range calculated by the<br />

ASF model indicates that A2's energy intensity improvement rates are<br />

one-third lower compared to the B2 scenaiio and less than half<br />

compared to the Bl scenario. By 2100, A2's final energy intensity is<br />

calculated by the ASF model at 5.9 MJ/$, which compai-e.s to the<br />

literature range of up to 7 MJ/$, and a value of 7.3 MJ/$ in the Л2-А1-<br />

MiniCAM scenario, which contains the highest energy-intensity<br />

trajectory within the 40 SRES scenarios. Thus, the A2 scenario's<br />

energy-intensity improvement rates are well within the uncertainty<br />

range as indicated by the scenario literature and are not considered<br />

overly pessimistic by the writing team. During the government review<br />

process, comment was made on the fact that energy intensities in A2<br />

are one-third higher than those in B2. This figure is classified as<br />

"reasonable" for an inter-family scenario variation by the writing team<br />

because it is consistent both with the underlying differences in per<br />

capita GDP (i.e. productivity) growth between the two scenario<br />

families and with the relationship between energy intensity<br />

improvements and шасго-economic producUvity giowth identified in<br />

the literature assessment in Chapters 2 and 3.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!