05.03.2014 Views

Emissions Scenarios - IPCC

Emissions Scenarios - IPCC

Emissions Scenarios - IPCC

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

An Overview of <strong>Scenarios</strong> 211<br />

availability might be much larger than assumed a decade ago.<br />

This finding also reflects the results of <strong>IPCC</strong> WGII SAR<br />

(Watson etal., 1996).<br />

4.4.6.5. Bl <strong>Scenarios</strong><br />

Assumpfions on the fossil fuel resource-base used in the Bl<br />

marker scenario quantification are based on the estimates of<br />

ultimately recoverable conventional and unconventional fossil<br />

resources described in Rogner (1997). The capital output ratio<br />

of resource exploitation is assumed to rise with progressive<br />

resource depletion, but this is counteracted by learning curve<br />

effects in the marker scenario quantification provided by the<br />

IMAGE model. Regional estimates of the exploitation costs of<br />

conventional and unconventional resources of Rogner (1997)<br />

were used to construct long-term supply cost curves as of 1971.<br />

These values, rather than absolute upper bounds on resource<br />

base availability, define future resource availability in the<br />

IMAGE model. The supposed availability of huge nonconventional<br />

occurrences of oil and natural gas, with a<br />

geographic distribution markedly different from the distribution<br />

of conventional oil and gas, has significant implications for fuel<br />

supply and trade patterns in the long term. For coal resources,<br />

Rogner's (1997) estimates were also adopted; of the total of 262<br />

ZJ, 58 ZJ belong to the categories of proved recoverable,<br />

additional recoverable, and additional identified coal resources.<br />

The production costs of coal were assumed to rise with<br />

increasing depth and rising labor wages, but these costs are<br />

largely offset by mechanization (in underground mining) and<br />

economies of scale (in surface mining).<br />

4.4.6.6. Harmonized and Other Bl <strong>Scenarios</strong><br />

The call on oil resources in the scenarios that comprise the В1<br />

scenario family ranges between 11 and 20 ZJ, with a median of<br />

17 ZJ (Bl marker, 20 ZJ). For gas the range is 15 to 33 ZJ<br />

(median, 20 ZJ; Bl marker, 15 ZJ), and for coal the<br />

corresponding range is between 3 and 27 ZJ (median, 11 ZJ;<br />

Bl marker, 13 ZJ). An overview is given in Figures 4-8 to 4-<br />

10.<br />

4.4.6.7. B2 <strong>Scenarios</strong><br />

The availability of fossil energy resources in the B2 marker<br />

scenario is assumed to be conservative, in line with the gradual,<br />

incremental change philosophy of the B2 scenario storyline.<br />

Consequentiy, oil and gas availability expands only gradually<br />

while coal continues to be abundant. Assumed oil and gas<br />

resource availability does not extend much beyond current<br />

conventional and unconventional reserves. Through gradual<br />

improvements in technology, a larger share of unconventional<br />

resei-ves and some additional resource categories are assumed<br />

to become available at improved costs over the 21" century.<br />

The availability of oil and gas, in particular, is Umited<br />

compared to the estimated magnitude of global fossil resources<br />

and occurrences (Watson et ai, 1996). This translates into<br />

relatively limited energy options in general and extends also to<br />

non-fossil energy options.<br />

4.4.6.8. Harmonized and Other B2 <strong>Scenarios</strong><br />

Altemative B2 scenario implementations assumed similar order<br />

of magnitudes of resource availability as the B2-marker scenario,<br />

except for B2High-MiniCAM. The resultant cumulative resource<br />

use (1990-2100) ranged between 9 and 23 ZJ (median, 17 ZJ; B2<br />

marker, 19 ZJ) for oil, between 18 and 27 ZJ (median, 21 ZJ; B2<br />

marker, 27 ZJ) for gas, and between 12 and 55 ZJ (median, 21<br />

ZJ; B2 marker, 13 ZJ) for coal (see Figures 4-8 to 4-10). The<br />

largest uncertainties relate to different inteipretations of the more<br />

gradual changes under a "dynamics-as-usual" philosophy that<br />

characterizes the B2 scenario storyline. One group of scenarios<br />

(including the B2 marker) assumed a gradual expansion in the<br />

availability of conventional and unconventional oil and gas,<br />

whereas another group of scenarios adopted more conservative<br />

assumptions (akin to the A2 and В1 scenario families).^'' All else<br />

being equal, lower resource-availability assumptions for oil and<br />

natural gas lead to a higher reliance on coal and non-fossil<br />

altematives and explain, together with technology assumptions,<br />

the differences in emissions between altemative В 2 scenario<br />

quantifications discussed in Chapter 5.<br />

4.4.7. Technological Change<br />

Chapter 3 highlights the importance of technological change in<br />

long-run productivity growth, but also for the historical<br />

transformations of energy end-use and supply systems. The<br />

importance of technological change in explaining wide-ranging<br />

outcomes in future emissions has been highlighted by Alcamo<br />

et al., (1995) and Grübler and Nakicenovic (1996), among<br />

others. The latter reference also provides a critical assessment<br />

of the previous IS92 scenario series and its comparison to the<br />

literature. Prominent scenario studies of possible technological<br />

change in future energy systems in the absence of climate<br />

policies include Ausubel et al. (1988), Edmonds et al. (1994,<br />

1996a), IIASA-WEC (1995), and Nakicenovic et al. (1998).<br />

Future technology characteristics must therefore be treated as<br />

dynamic, with future improvement rates subject to considerable<br />

uncertainty. This is reflected in the SRES scenarios that adopt a<br />

wide range of improvement rates for energy extraction,<br />

conversion, and end-use technologies (Table 4-11). The actual<br />

representation of technological change in the six SRES models<br />

ranges from exogenously prescribed availability, through cost<br />

and performance profiles (which in some cases also include<br />

consumer or end-use costs for technology use), to stylized<br />

representation of leaming processes.^' Yet, as summarized in<br />

Chapter 3, model representations of technological change are<br />

poorly developed, although evolving rapidly.<br />

^" Resource availability assumptions also appear to be rather model<br />

specific in this scenario family. For instance, in many scenarios<br />

pattems of resource availability resemble the hypotheses retained by<br />

a particular model used for quantification of a marker scenario in one<br />

of the other three scenario families.<br />

'^ Roehrl and Riahi (2000) provide a description of the methodology<br />

of representing technological change in MESSAGE as used here in<br />

the SRES scenarios.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!