25.07.2014 Views

annotated bibliography of fisheries economics literature - Office of ...

annotated bibliography of fisheries economics literature - Office of ...

annotated bibliography of fisheries economics literature - Office of ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

This paper explores how the economic value <strong>of</strong> recreation at local public<br />

beaches can be estimated from nearby property values. The negative effect <strong>of</strong><br />

distance from the nearest public beach on coastal property values was used to<br />

reveal recreational value. Estimates <strong>of</strong> recreational value were also compared<br />

to the costs <strong>of</strong> beach nourishment that were calculated from a simulation <strong>of</strong><br />

beach erosion caused, in part, by increases in relative sea-level. Although a<br />

complete benefit-cost analysis was not feasible, the results suggest that<br />

potential losses <strong>of</strong> recreational value by local users alone could establish<br />

the efficiency <strong>of</strong> beach nourishment projects.<br />

Edwards, Steven F. and Steven A. Murawski (1993). Potential Economic<br />

Benefits from Efficient Harvest <strong>of</strong> New England Groundfish. North<br />

American Journal <strong>of</strong> Fisheries Management, 13: 437-449.<br />

Dissipation <strong>of</strong> economic benefits from commercial harvest <strong>of</strong> the<br />

multispecies groundfish resource in U.S. waters <strong>of</strong>f New England was estimated<br />

from dynamic optimization <strong>of</strong> empirical bioeconomic models. Net economic value<br />

could be maximized by an estimate 70% reduction in fishing effort, resulting<br />

in a sevenfold increase in the size <strong>of</strong> the harvestable resource and a<br />

threefold increase in sustainable yield. Under these conditions, fishers,<br />

seafood industries, and consumers could benefit from an estimated US$150<br />

million increase in sustainable net economic value each year, including about<br />

$130 million in resource rent. Consumers in the region could pr<strong>of</strong>it further<br />

from the nutritional and health benefits <strong>of</strong> up to an additional 6 lb <strong>of</strong> fresh<br />

fish per capita. Policies to achieve these benefits are highlighted.<br />

Augmenting state ownership <strong>of</strong> the resource with market transfers <strong>of</strong> individual<br />

effort or harvest quotas is preferred to open access, but common property or<br />

individual private property regimes are more likely to benefit society.<br />

Edwards, S., Al Bejda, and A. Richards (1991). "Sole Ownership <strong>of</strong><br />

Living Marine Resources: A Possible Solution to Overfishing."<br />

Draft report prepared by the Northeast Fisheries Center Research<br />

Council, September 5.<br />

This report explores the meaning and application <strong>of</strong> sole ownership <strong>of</strong><br />

living marine resources with the purpose <strong>of</strong> promoting an informed and timely<br />

discussion <strong>of</strong> its utility and feasibility. The major findings and conclusions<br />

are: (1) fish resources are the only publicly owned natural resources in the<br />

United States that are both widely subject to open access and available to<br />

harvesters at no cost; (2) both overfishing and the resultant dissipation <strong>of</strong><br />

billions <strong>of</strong> dollars <strong>of</strong> resource value result from the absence <strong>of</strong> well defined<br />

(i.e. permanent, enforceable, and transferable) property rights to the living<br />

marine resources; (3)fishery quotas and effort restrictions address only the<br />

symptoms <strong>of</strong> open access, not the fundamental problem <strong>of</strong> a lack <strong>of</strong> property<br />

rights to the resource and its productivity; (4) the incentives that influence<br />

decisions <strong>of</strong> fishermen and public <strong>of</strong>ficials are fundamental to the presence <strong>of</strong><br />

both "market failure" and "government failure;" (5) sole ownership--not<br />

limited entry or ITQs--could provide resource owners with the necessary<br />

incentives to husband the fish resources.<br />

Edwards, S., Allen J. Bejda, and A. Richards (1993). "Sole Ownership <strong>of</strong><br />

Living Marine Resources." NOAA Technical Memorandum NMFS-F/NEC-<br />

99, U.S. Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce, National Oceanic and Atmospheric<br />

Administration, National Marine Fisheries Service, Northeast<br />

Region, Northeast Fisheries Science Center, May, 21 pp.<br />

This report explores the meaning and application <strong>of</strong> sole ownership <strong>of</strong><br />

living marine resources. Its purpose was to promote an informed and timely<br />

1 8 3

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!