07.03.2014 Aufrufe

soziologie und gesellschaftliche entwicklung (35 mb) - ISF München

soziologie und gesellschaftliche entwicklung (35 mb) - ISF München

soziologie und gesellschaftliche entwicklung (35 mb) - ISF München

MEHR ANZEIGEN
WENIGER ANZEIGEN

Erfolgreiche ePaper selbst erstellen

Machen Sie aus Ihren PDF Publikationen ein blätterbares Flipbook mit unserer einzigartigen Google optimierten e-Paper Software.

is clearer. Actually, also rational expectations are "natural": once the<br />

market is defined as the monetarists do, these expectations have to be<br />

rational, otherwise the market would not be natural. Moreover, the relevant<br />

model needs "an additional sociological condition which entails perceived<br />

and actual unanimity of beliefs across all agents in the model" (Frydman<br />

and Phelps, 1983). In fact, testing statistically the REH has been fo<strong>und</strong><br />

a prohibitive task: "the assumption of optimal use of the available Information<br />

cannot be tested independently of an assumption about the available<br />

Information" (Buiter, 1980). In the end, the result of all this is entirely<br />

paradoxical. Crises, Stagnation, social misery do not really exist. If they<br />

are present, it can only be the result of State interference with what would<br />

otherwise be a natural Optimum equilibrium. But why isn't the State as<br />

"natural" as other agents? Why shouldn't there be "natural" institutions? 4<br />

Only by removing the social aspects of reality, monetarists can build their<br />

own specific "natural"-neutral world.<br />

b) The neo-keynesians<br />

Much of this thinking is a reaction to the neo-keynesian school that had<br />

developed an Interpretation of economic phenomena which, utilising some<br />

of Keynes' ideas, focused the attention on the labor market, represented<br />

by the well-known Phillips curve (Phillips 1958, Lipsey 1960, Samuelson<br />

and Solow 1960) . This is a relationship which makes money wages dependent<br />

inversely on unemployment; as money wages are considered the<br />

main source of inflation (cost-push inflation), that relationship was used<br />

to explain it: when unemployment decreases, money wages increase, and<br />

prices with them. Public policy, therefore, consists in determining the<br />

acceptable level of the couple inflation — unemployment. This construction<br />

was destroyed by the long period of Stagflation following the break between<br />

the dollar and gold (1968-71) and the oil crises (1973 to 1980) -<br />

as is well known, high unemployment went hand in hand with high inflation.<br />

Monetarists have objected to this hypothesis, because it is built on the<br />

basis of money-illusion: as workers are not fools (and bear rational expectations),<br />

they will reckon their wages in real terms; if increases in money<br />

wages bring about inflation, and no increase in real wages, they will either<br />

settle for wage indexation or stop contracting for higher money wages.<br />

Thus, the Phillips curve does not exist, there is no trade-off between<br />

unemployment and inflation, and the latter is never due to private economic<br />

agents, but to public policy, which increases money supply in order<br />

to fight unemployment (which, as we have seen, according to monetarists<br />

does not really exist).<br />

There is little doubt that the social vision of neo-keynesians was (and<br />

is) füll of deficiencies. Thus, to suppose that public policies do not engender<br />

Lutz (1984): Soziologie <strong>und</strong> <strong>gesellschaftliche</strong> Entwicklung.<br />

URN: http://nbn-resolving.de/urn:nbn:de:0168-ssoar-100776

Hurra! Ihre Datei wurde hochgeladen und ist bereit für die Veröffentlichung.

Erfolgreich gespeichert!

Leider ist etwas schief gelaufen!