07.03.2014 Aufrufe

soziologie und gesellschaftliche entwicklung (35 mb) - ISF München

soziologie und gesellschaftliche entwicklung (35 mb) - ISF München

soziologie und gesellschaftliche entwicklung (35 mb) - ISF München

MEHR ANZEIGEN
WENIGER ANZEIGEN

Sie wollen auch ein ePaper? Erhöhen Sie die Reichweite Ihrer Titel.

YUMPU macht aus Druck-PDFs automatisch weboptimierte ePaper, die Google liebt.

ut mostly the reference is to the liberal economic school that Keynes, with a misnomer,<br />

called "the Classics". This school is essentially anti-keynesian, and has<br />

decided to dress the colors of Keynes' enemies. Although extremist, this school is<br />

academically well accepted. And because it is extremist, it appeals to extreme<br />

liberals — including those that feel the urge to "change the System". It is not uncommon<br />

today to find similar extremists in the "left wing": they generally don't<br />

know the cultural roots of their own extremism.<br />

3 Although less appealing than the perfect competition utopia. The "natural" enterprise<br />

is totally autocratic, does not distinguish between the owners of the enterprise<br />

and its managers, and all its components can be measured in price terms and<br />

disaggregated at will.<br />

4 This, by the way, is a problem for those politicians in Government that profess neomonetarist<br />

principles: they would have to be continuously self-effacing; but in<br />

order to make their ideas believed they have to exercise force, much beyond what<br />

would be natural. Thus, we have liberalism by "diktat" in Great Britain, and a<br />

Shacht-type keynesianism in the U.S.<br />

5 I shall not quote the immense literature on the Phillips curve. Suffice it to say that<br />

all neo-keynesians have subscribed it (Samuelson, Solow, Modigliani, Tobin) as well<br />

as some post-keynesians (Kahn) and even young marxists (Rawthorne) — the latter<br />

taking the inflation-unemployment trade-off as a sign of class struggle.<br />

6 If so, and contrary to monetarist opinion, real wages will increase, due to the quasirent<br />

accruing to a labor monopoly.<br />

7 Keynes, in fact, recognized that workers can only determine money wages, while<br />

real wages are determined by enterprises — that control prices. This did not mean,<br />

however, that real wages are considered as given: Keynes' point was intended to<br />

show that effective demand could not be systematically sustained by an increase<br />

in money wages.<br />

8 It is interesting to note that the term "structural" has completely changed meaning<br />

over the last two decades: it was originally associated, with reference to unemployment,<br />

to <strong>und</strong>erdeveloped areas, where the problem was recognized as being rather<br />

that of accumulation than of a lack of effective demand; this justified aid policies<br />

in favor of such areas — a "progressive" idea. Today, the term "structural" is<br />

applied to well developed economies, in order to justify the recent, large unemployment<br />

rates; if unemployment is structural only faster accumulation can remedy it,<br />

and this will take place only if the rate of profit is sufficiently high. In this manner,<br />

a redistribution of income against wages and in favor of profits becomes the best<br />

means to reduce "structural" unemployment. Monetarists are slightly less naive,<br />

as they leave to enterprises' decisions to determine what is the natural rate of unemployment;<br />

but there is no doubt that if the "natural investment rate" rises, then<br />

also the natural employment rate will rise. As an aside, let us remind ourselves that<br />

if both developed and <strong>und</strong>erdeveloped areas have structural or natural unemployment,<br />

the case for an aid policy in favor of the latter becomes very weak — both<br />

areas will be considered as differing due to "natural" causes.<br />

9 This implies that the (cost) supply curve of each enterprise is not increasing (Jossa,<br />

1981) and that the demand curve for each product does not contribute to determining<br />

prices, which therefore reflect production costs. In the economic System,<br />

then, effective aggregate demand determines aggregate supply, but individual supply<br />

curves determine prices. If aggregate (not the specific commodity's) demand could<br />

be shown to influence all individual supply curves — in the sense that unit cost<br />

curves will decline (rise) more the greater is the increase (decrease) in aggregate<br />

demand (Leon, 1981) — then the change in aggregate demand, through individual<br />

firms' cost curves, would have an influence on prices and, therefore, on income<br />

distribution. Sraffa (1960) showed that income distribution is determined outside<br />

the economic System ( he thought that the interest rate, via the keynesian liquidity<br />

Lutz (1984): Soziologie <strong>und</strong> <strong>gesellschaftliche</strong> Entwicklung.<br />

URN: http://nbn-resolving.de/urn:nbn:de:0168-ssoar-100776

Hurra! Ihre Datei wurde hochgeladen und ist bereit für die Veröffentlichung.

Erfolgreich gespeichert!

Leider ist etwas schief gelaufen!