07.03.2014 Aufrufe

soziologie und gesellschaftliche entwicklung (35 mb) - ISF München

soziologie und gesellschaftliche entwicklung (35 mb) - ISF München

soziologie und gesellschaftliche entwicklung (35 mb) - ISF München

MEHR ANZEIGEN
WENIGER ANZEIGEN

Sie wollen auch ein ePaper? Erhöhen Sie die Reichweite Ihrer Titel.

YUMPU macht aus Druck-PDFs automatisch weboptimierte ePaper, die Google liebt.

sense that they can influence demand (welfare transfers), and a degree of<br />

monopsony in the sense that they can influence supply (government welfare<br />

financing). The result of all this is that füll employment will not be<br />

assured, as — again following Keynes — there is no reason to suppose that<br />

market forces (or autonomous social behaviour) produce necessarily füll<br />

employment (or effectiveness). Two outcomes are then logically possible:<br />

the first is that Government will find it ever more difficult to obtain fuller<br />

employment by increasing welfare expenditure, if the market does not<br />

produce füll employment by itself; the second is that the egalitarian motivations<br />

behind welfare gradually change to charity motivations.<br />

Society will soon find that welfare is economically and socially useless,<br />

while the market is the real force that determines (less than füll) employment.<br />

Neokeynesians sensed this, and thought that a policy to minimize<br />

wages, compensated by welfare, could stimulate private investment — a<br />

mediation which however lacks the power to oblige enterprises to accumulate,<br />

and leaves to market forces the determination of investment and<br />

employment. Monetarists, more radically, throw away welfare and recognize<br />

the powers of the market ("natural" social behaviour; or the "natural"<br />

development thereof). They negate any strength to the multiplier — not<br />

only of welfare expenditures, but of all autonomous expenditures — thus<br />

freeing the market from any links with public policy.<br />

The Welfare State, so modified or reduced, opens up new vistas, not<br />

particularly optimistic, for societal change. As it tends to become charity<br />

on the one hand, and to reinforce the "efficiency" of public institutions<br />

on the other, while leaving market forces free to operate and to create<br />

stable long-term unemployment, somewhere in the social System a new<br />

class division may appear. What we thought in the past were signs of social<br />

progress — the development of mass movements based on voluntary aggregation<br />

and formed outside the institutional set-up — may yet be interpreted<br />

as a spontaneous adaptation of society to the liberation of market<br />

forces, the disgregation of the welfare State, the reproduction of a divided<br />

society, based on mass unemployment, crises and slow economic growth.<br />

Economists, as intellectuals, have simply sensed this societal change —<br />

and have used their tools to justify it. If saddened by our role, it is nevertheless<br />

fascinating to see the mechanisms at work: wehave,infact, witnessed<br />

the social creation of ideology. As an economist, I would welcome sociologists<br />

interested in examining — in corpore — the sociology of ideology.<br />

ANMERKUNGEN<br />

1 Not all monetarists adhere to the rational expectation hypothesis (Frydman-Phelps,<br />

1983); they fear that such hypothesis is "closer in spirit to a planned economy than<br />

to a decentralized market, due to the relevant model" (q.v.).<br />

2 Some reference to Smith, Ricardo, Malthus or Marx, due to the "natural" concepts;<br />

Lutz (1984): Soziologie <strong>und</strong> <strong>gesellschaftliche</strong> Entwicklung.<br />

URN: http://nbn-resolving.de/urn:nbn:de:0168-ssoar-100776

Hurra! Ihre Datei wurde hochgeladen und ist bereit für die Veröffentlichung.

Erfolgreich gespeichert!

Leider ist etwas schief gelaufen!